Drought map via NOAA Yellow is lower level drought, dark red is higher |
The Globe and Mail
Report on Business (01 August 2014, p B1, B8) ran a report on how
rising prices are starting to impact consumer meat choices, and how
that's affecting the bottom line of Maple Leaf Meats (who are
currently restructuring). The article points out how bacon prices are
up by about 26 percent and pork chops are up 18 percent, even though
Statistics Canada claims prices are only up 3 percent from a year
earlier.
There are a number
of reasons offered for the rise in meat prices; the arrival of a
piglet-killing virus (porcine epidemic diarrhoea) which has driven up
the cost of a pig by 24 percent, the drought of 2012 that drove up
the cost of feed and led to herd culls, and a 5 percent depreciation
of the Canadian dollar pushing prices higher north of the border. BMO
Capital Markets economist Aaron Goertzen takes the “most obvious
statement of the year” award by pointing out that consumers are
avoiding the now-pricier beef and pork by buying chicken or cheaper
kinds of protein.
But one reason for
higher prices gets no traction in the article at all—or indeed
pretty much anywhere else with the exception of the New England Complex Systems Institute (NECSI). NECSI has been warning about the
influence of futures traders in the food system for several years
now. As did Matt Taibbi in Griftopia: bubble machines, vampiresquids, and the long con that is breaking America (2010),
upon which I'm relying for for describing the system.
In
a functioning commodity market, there are three players; buyers,
sellers, and speculators called futures traders. Buyers and sellers
(farmers and food companies) can arrange contracts with each other to
guarantee the price of a commodity like wheat or corn (or pretty much
any other physical substance, like platinum or oil). A producer wants
to ensure that they get a fair price for their wheat, so they offer a
future delivery for an agreed-upon price. This works for a buyer, as
they want to have a certain and non-fluctuating price for the
commodity they need. Called physical hedging,
these contracts allow an amount of certainty in an uncertain world.
If the price of a commodity rises unexpectedly, the producer forgoes
some profit in exchange for a guaranteed price. If the price drops,
the buyer forgoes some profit in exchange for a guaranteed price.
But
to fully function, there needs to be another player: the speculator.
Their role is to guarantee
that the physical hedgers, the buyers and sellers of commodities,
always have a place to buy or sell. If
you bring a commodity to market and there are no buyers at the moment
(even for future delivery), you still want to sell your product. The
speculator buys the contract, offering a discounted price (because
there's a lot of supply, but less demand). Later, when buyers come to
market looking for product, the speculator offers the contract for
some percentage over what they paid (higher demand, lower supply).
This
works well, moderating price spikes as long as the
speculators are watched very carefully.
If speculators are allowed to buy all of a commodity (or contracts on
future delivery of that commodity) or even a significant percentage
of the contracts or commodity, this creates a condition of artificial
scarcity which allows the speculator to manipulate the price. As Matt
Taibbi puts it “[T]he government sets up position limits, which
guarantee that at any given moment, the trading on the commodity
market would be dominated by the physical hedgers, with the
speculators playing a purely functional role in the margins to keep
things running smoothly”. This system ensures that the speculators
will make a reasonable steady profit—but not the massive, crazy
profit levels that market manipulation offer.
So
in 1991, the Commodity Futures Trading Commission re-defined
speculators as physical hedgers, and freed at least 16 very
large companies (including
the vampire squid that is Goldman Sachs)
to pursue unlimited futures speculation in the commodity markets.
This was kept very very quiet, and by 2008, fully 80 percent of the
action on the commodity exchanges was speculative.
But
not just anyone could speculate on the commodity exchanges—you had
to be one of the 16 companies allowed to do this. And those 16
companies had set themselves up as the unavoidable middlemen in
commodities index speculation.
You
remember 2008, right? The year the bubble burst and countries around
the world took the hit to keep the one percent in Maseratis and
mansions? The year we bailed out the various vampire squid that lied,
cheated, and stole everything that wasn't nailed down (and a lot that
was)? Well, a lot of money went looking for a new home that wasn't a
falsified Collateral Debt Obligation or one of the many other
fraudulent products that had been peddled hither and yon.
“So why not bet on something people can't do without—like food or gas or oil? What could be safer than that? As if people will ever stop buying gasoline! Or wheat! Hell, this is America. Motherfuckers be eating pasta and cran muffins by the metric ton for the next ten centuries! Look at the asses of people in this country. Just let them try to cut back on wheat, and sugar, and corn!At least that's what Goldman Sachs told its institutional investors back in 2005, in a pamphlet entitled Investing and Trading in the Goldman Sachs Commodities Index, given out mainly to pension funds and the like.” (Taibbi, Griftopia, 2010. pp. 141, 142)
And
that money, heading into the commodities market, has screwed things
up ever since. When a hundred million dollars is often enough to
completely eat a commodity class, this skews the market, driving up
prices for consumers. This type of speculation is hoarding, creating
an artificial scarcity that drives prices north for no reason except
to provide speculative return. And while you and I have bank accounts
that return nothing at all in interest, speculative big money has
access to different investments than we do, and a demand for big
returns (like a steady 10 percent, for example). And if you control
supply, and therefore price at market, you can pretty much define
what return you want to get. Ten percent compounded will double your
money in about seven years. And who wouldn't want that?
While
there are temporary or local shortages in various commodities, like
drought in the US, these are not enough to explain the increases
we're seeing in commodity prices. Worldwide, for example, oil
production has remained steady or even risen. But prices at the pump
haven't reflected this. Pump prices reflect one influence only—the
impact of massive amounts of money being invested in the commodity
markets driving up prices. This isn't classical free markets. This is
monopoly market capitalism. Access isn't available to everyone,
markets aren't transparent, and Adam Smith's* “invisible hand”
has been ground under a bankster's** boot into
a bloody pulp. This is late stage capital stripping every last bit of
value before abandoning our countries to some new status that's even
lower than what we think of as “third world”.
It's
all very disheartening (or, more honestly, terrifying). But there are
signs of hope—at least I see them as signs of hope. I was passing a
house the other day and saw a familiar sight; an upholstered chair at
the curb with a “free” sign on it. The chair probably cost three
or four hundred dollars when it was purchased about ten years back.
Making it worth maybe $25 at a second-hand store that would accept
it as a donation. But the owners knew that the chair had a value, and
probably more than $25. They knew what it had cost, how it had been
used, and that it had an ongoing value. But they were willing to
forgo that value if someone would find the chair useful.
Think
how many times you've done the same thing: given something away
because its value had dropped for you and someone else could use it.
I've got five or six dozen one litre mason
jars that were given to me by a complete stranger. Mason jars don't
really lose value—they're maybe not endlessly reusable, but
certainly have very long life-spans.
I'm
also a member of Victoria Freecycle, an email listserv that allows
people to offer stuff for reuse before trashing or recycling. It's
another way to recognize value in use. Then there's Freeskool, where
people that know stuff teach people who want to learn stuff (last
year I learned how to make toothpaste at home). Or the group of
younger folk fed up with their cell service providers who are working
toward a not-for-profit Co-op
model cell service (and receive tremendous outpourings of practical
support when they bring the
topic up in public forums. I expect their Kickstarter to be a runaway
success).
The
gift economy, Co-operatives,
CSAs (Community Supported Agriculture, where people absorb some of
the risk faced by farmers in exchange for a share of the production).
All of these and more are showing that we recognize that the
capitalist economy is just
something we made up and if we
want to, we can make something different up.
If
we take a little stroll away from the current system, if we have a
little faith in each other, treat each other a little better, we can
make everything a little more resilient, more sustainable, more
human.
* It
is interesting to learn that Adam Smith was instructed in how the
economy worked by Scots who were themselves slave-holding absentee
producers working land taken by genocide. This may have skewed their
economic worldview.
** Bankster = Banker + gangster. Certainly in use in the 1980s. I wouldn't be surprised if it pre-dated the Great Depression.
** Bankster = Banker + gangster. Certainly in use in the 1980s. I wouldn't be surprised if it pre-dated the Great Depression.
No comments:
Post a Comment